the basis for the Christian Bible New
Testament, which was actually compiled by a different set of prophets.
An interesting
characteristic of religious organizations emanated from the Protestant
Reformation; secular mechanisms were instituted to deal with what we might term
the more mundane aspects of religious congregation governance. In some
instances, the entire congregation of a local church may act on certain issues
such as the selection of a new pastor for that church. For issues such as
keeping physical facilities in good repair and making sure all the bills get
paid, an elected body is often selected by the congregation. For some religious
organizations, a hierarchy of such elected bodies serves to coordinate the more
secular policy considerations for a large collection of churches. Thus, within
protestant Christianity we see the mechanism of both religious and secular
governance social systems.
Solon was a
Greek philosopher, statesman and politician who lived around 600 B.C. Due to
his widespread popularity among all the social ranks of the city-state of Athens, he was tasked with revising the
political system of the day. He did this by writing a well-defined constitution
and then adapting the laws to this constitutional framework. His system
replaced heredity as the basis for being or selecting the leadership with a
social structure where, according to Encyclopedia
Britannica (1910 edition), “Solon made property the measure of political
power, and confined the higher offices of state to the wealthiest citizens; but
election to these offices was to be made by the whole body of the people, the
tenure of office was limited as to time, and an account had to be rendered
publicly as to its exercise.” Naturally, as he developed the first tenets of
democracy, there was still a long way to universal suffrage from citizens with
equal rights. However, while the constitutional government that he established
was ultimately overthrown, much of the set of civil laws that he established
survived. Today, we tend to refer to the legislators that we elect to our
various policy making bodies as “solons.” Moreover, the name of the Athenian
public assembly, “Ecclesia,” has come to mean church (“Église” in French), a
matter not without importance for ontological discussions later in this
chapter.
Within a
democratic domain, the source of policy is the collective action of the solons
representing some assembly of people. A variety of mechanisms are found around
the world for elected representatives to effect policy. In the United States, unicameral and bicameral federal and
state legislative systems encompass both a law making body as well as a
parallel administrative function. In the United Kingdom, the parliamentary system has both
legislative and administrative functions. In the United States, state institutions have their own trust
and policy infrastructures, with parallel administrative functions, and those
institutions are subject to policies established by the federal government.
Additionally, non governmental entities like public companies also come with
their trust and policy infrastructures, in the form of board and management,
subject to state and federal policies.
The governance
of consequences is central to any social ecosystem. Beyond a purely objective
identification and enforcement of consequences, a social ecosystem has at the
pinnacle of its controlling architecture an arbiter with ultimate authority for
the application of consequences. There are three distinct variants of such
arbiters found within the primary social ecosystems of the United States. Within religious systems are found the
clergy, often organized within some ascending hierarchy that culminates in a
controlling figure or group within respective religious denominations. There is
no all encompassing trust infrastructure for all religions, nor is there a
|