computer at each mutational point. This
evolution typically involved new systems being brought into the market to
address uses around the periphery of the mainstream of computer systems. The
new machines then tended to establish a shift in the mainstream toward these
new uses. The major enabler of this evolutionary progression has been the
dramatic enhancements to processors, memory and peripheral mass storage devices
which for decades have followed the general progression of Moore’s
Law, the idea that electronic circuit capabilities double every eighteen
months.
The impetus of this evolutionary
progression has been the development of new tools to address more, and more
fully, the individual and cumulative needs of the ascending needs hierarchy.
Such evolutionary forces continue today, and we note that the highest order
needs are now coming into the focus of the prospects of enhanced tool systems.
The physical ecosystem is seldom in a
state of quiescence; biological entities evolve, mechanical systems are
modified and the environment changes. Within this developmental turbulence, the
nature of the fittest vis-à-vis
natural selection seems always in a state of flux. The same is true of social
ecosystems. This is certainly the case with computers and computer networks;
specifically with respect to the Internet and its derivative Web. As we noted
earlier, in a time of great flux, it is difficult to assess the direction of
change simultaneously with a determination of current effective policies of the
social order. However, what we can do is reflect on the forces that drive
change because within social ecosystems these forces derive largely from the
human needs hierarchy. Consequently, we think it to be an interesting exercise
to consider the stimuli at work in the current evolutionary mix which provides
impetus for change to existing network structures and mechanisms. The Internet
derived from the societal deficiency needs of physiological support coupled to
safety and security. The major driver of Internet architecture was redundancy
in physical connectivity and switching in the face of war or natural disaster.
The extension of the Internet through the facilities of the Web provided
additional mechanisms to sate the appetites of the higher order stimuli of the needs
hierarchy. This extension is incomplete as it relates to fully replicating the
mechanisms of human social orders. These deficiencies form the guideposts of
our considerations.
We’ve previously considered the three
most significant entities in the location and conveyance of content on the Web:
the consumer whose appetites must be sated, the content provider that offers
sustenance and the broker (middleman) that is typically positioned between the
two and enables their subsequent interactions, for a small fee of course. Each
of these parties has a personal or institutional interest in facilitating
business models with certain characteristics. The consumer is driven by needs based
stimuli, which on an instantaneous basis might present very asymmetric cost
benefit assessments: “I need it, and I need it now! Price is no object!” Or, “That
content should be a commodity that I can obtain for free!” The provider may
have a different priority assessment, also needs based: “I must get this much
for my product or I can’t afford to stay in business!” Or, “My work is unique,
it can’t he had from anywhere else, so I should be compensated accordingly.”
Finally, the middleman is in the position to put the two together. In fact, the
middleman is often the infrastructure initiator; the developer of mechanisms to
bring consumer and provider together. As a consequence, the middleman may feel
it only just to charge a “small fee” that is a significant fraction of the
total value equation. These business models translate into operational and
technical tugs of war that impact heavily on new systems.
|